We assume no dividend and positive risk-free interest rate.
European put-call parity
European put and call option with same maturity and strike satisfy the put-call parity:
where is the price of European call option, is the price of the European put option, is the price of the underlying asset at time .
can be seen as a forward contract with maturity and strike . A short proof of European put-call parity is as follows:
That is to say the terminal payoff of long call and short put is equal to that of forward (with the same maturity and strike ). Hence,
where is the discount factor from to , and is the expectation under the risk neutral measure. Above equation is equivalent to the European put-call parity formula.
Never prematurely exercise American call option
If we wait until maturity, the profit of the call option is . If we exercise the option at time , then we have cash position and a stock the worth at this time. Then, at time , the total portfolio value would be . That is
But if the underlying asset pays a dividend, then it might be optimal to exercise the call option early.
American put-call parity
American put and call option satisfies the following inequality:
For the first inequality,
Suppose at time 0, we have the following portfolio: long a call option, short a put option, short underlying asset, and have cash.
At , the portfolio value is .
If the long position side of the put option decides to exercise the option, we then exercise our call option at the same time, otherwise, wait until maturity to decide exercise or not. With this strategy, call and put has the same exercise time and hence can be seen as a forward with maturity undetermined. Say, the maturity is .
Then, at time , the value of our portfolio is for the option part and for the asset and cash part. The total value of the portfolio is .
By the non-arbitrage principal, we have
For the second inequality,